In previous columns (see Sept. 5 and Sept. 19 issues of The Central New York Business Journal) we have explored the economics of health care based on the challenging questions from patients that Dr. Michael Kirsch, a practicing physician and newspaper columnist, has lamented that he has difficulty answering. This week, we address his question, […]
Get Instant Access to This Article
Become a Central New York Business Journal subscriber and get immediate access to all of our subscriber-only content and much more.
- Critical Central New York business news and analysis updated daily.
- Immediate access to all subscriber-only content on our website.
- Get a year's worth of the Print Edition of The Central New York Business Journal.
- Special Feature Publications such as the Book of Lists and Revitalize Greater Binghamton, Mohawk Valley, and Syracuse Magazines
Click here to purchase a paywall bypass link for this article.
In previous columns (see Sept. 5 and Sept. 19 issues of The Central New York Business Journal) we have explored the economics of health care based on the challenging questions from patients that Dr. Michael Kirsch, a practicing physician and newspaper columnist, has lamented that he has difficulty answering. This week, we address his question, “Why is it possible that so many working Americans can’t afford medical-insurance coverage?”
The question presumes that Americans who choose not to have insurance coverage do so because they cannot afford it. This is the same mistake that policymakers, who cry that we have a “health-care crisis,” have made for decades.
The idea of a so-called crisis in health care began long before President Obama. It came on the heels of the birth of the private health-insurance industry.
Accident insurance for injuries incurred while working on the railroad or on steamboats originated around 1850. The first insurance that covered medical expenses emerged in 1929 as part of the original Blue Cross plans.
In 1932, the Committee on the Costs of Medical Care published a report calling for universal health insurance. It said, “The committee recommends the extension of all basic public health services — whether provided by governmental or nongovernmental agencies — so that they will be available to the entire population according to its needs.”
Harry Truman called for government-provided health insurance in 1945, ironically coinciding with the health-insurance industry’s era of greatest growth. According to the BlueCross BlueShield website timeline, “The spread of health insurance coverage — from less than 10 percent of the population having coverage in 1940 — grows to nearly 70 percent in 1955.” By 2005, “BlueCross and BlueShield system-wide enrollment reaches 93 million Americans — nearly one-in-three,” and that is just one health-insurance provider.
Health-care options in the United States were by any accurate medical measure the best in the world and getting better. However, in 1966 the government instituted the incentives that have done the most to drive up health-care prices: pushing the people using most of the resources, the elderly, onto Medicare.
Before health insurance, patients had to decide how much medical care was worth to them. Even now, many patients ask, “How much are healthy teeth worth to me?” because dental insurance is not standard coverage under health-care plans. And last year, 38.4 percent of adult Americans decided dental care wasn’t even worth the cost of one dental visit and didn’t have one.
Alas, such cost-benefit analysis is a foreign experience for most health-care patients. With the third-party-payer system, people don’t have to ask those questions. They can presume their health is worth the cost because they are able to purchase health care for only a fifth of the price.
The positive outcome is that even those who are sick and poor can acquire care. But it carries the inevitable negative outcome of waste. The “I’m already over my deductible so why not get the procedure done” mentality makes our country spend more on health care.
This mentality is not just encouraged, it is the most strategic given the third-party-payer system. To avoid its waste, the payment scheme needs to be changed. And to undo the effects of the third-party payer system, we must first undo portions of our current legislation. Here are our proposals.
- Although national health expenditures might be 17.9 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), our out-of-pocket spending is only 2 percent of GDP. Thus, because of the third-party-payer system, there is no disincentive for Americans to care about their own contribution to national health expenditures. Currently, the best we can do is to hope that not every American chooses to take advantage of his/her free colonoscopy.
- However, if there weren’t co-pays and there weren’t free procedures, then there wouldn’t be as much room to abuse the system. That’s why our first proposal is that a deductible should truly be the down payment it is meant to be.
- The Affordable Care Act required insurance companies to give away, either for free or with a co-pay, a whole array of procedures and goodies. This was a mistake. Insurance should be limited to a safety net to help families facing catastrophic expenses.
- Second, hospitals and doctors should be required to publish their charges in advance of treatment. There should not be different charges based on side deals that favor anyone except the patient.
- Doctors should be allowed to charge insurance companies for the additional documentation they require. And they should be permitted to give patients paying out of pocket a cash discount when payment can be collected at the time of the visit.
- Lastly, most of our national health expenditure goes for those 65 and older. Their spending is five times higher than children and three times higher than working-age people. Medicare and Medicaid spending accounts for 36 percent of our national health expenditure.
- Medicare is funded in part by a 2.9 percent tax paid by the employer and employee. If that money was put into a health-savings account for the benefit of the worker rather than going to supplement senior premiums, the worker would easily have enough saved by age 65 to cover medical expenses and premiums for themselves. This is our third proposal: either remove Medicare entirely or turn the program into a mandated health-savings program.
In short, we need to remove governmental force and monopolistic pressures and allow market forces to better allocate spending and control prices. We must return, as much as possible, to a fee-for-service approach to health care and restore the traditional doctor-patient relationship. And we need to assist low-income families directly without warping the supply-and-demand curves of the entire industry.
David John Marotta is president of Marotta Wealth Management, Inc. providing fee-only financial planning and wealth management at www.emarotta.com. Megan Russell studied cognitive science at the University of Virginia and now specializes in explaining the complexities of economics and finance at www.marottaonmoney.com